TOWARDS A GLOBAL RULING CLASS?:
GLOBALIZATION AND THE TRANSNATIONAL CAPITALIST CLASS
BY: WILLIAM I. ROBINSON AND JERRY HARRIS
NOTE: THIS ARTICLE APPEARED IN THE JOURNAL SCIENCE AND SOCIETY,
VOL. 64, NO. 1, SPRING 2000, PP. 11-54
PLEASE CITE ACCORDINGLY
ABSTRACT: A transnational capitalist class (TCC) has emerged as that segment of the world bourgeoisie that represents transnational capital, the owners of the leading worldwide means of production as embodied in the transnational corporations and private financial institutions. The spread of TNCs, the sharp increase in foreign direct investment, the proliferation of mergers and acquisitions across national borders, the rise of a global financial system, and the increased interlocking of positions within the global corporate structure, are some empirical indicators of the transnational integration of capitalists. The TCC manages global rather than national circuits of accumulation. This gives it an objective class existence and identity spatially and politically in the global system above any local territories and polities. The TCC became politicized from the 1970s into the 1990s and has pursued a class project of capitalist globalization institutionalized in an emergent transnational state apparatus and in a "Third Way" political program. The emergent global capitalist historic bloc is divided over strategic issues of class rule and how to achieve regulatory order in the global economy. Contradictions within the ruling bloc open up new opportunities for emancipatory projects from global labor.
It is widely recognized that world capitalism has been undergoing a period of profound restructuring since the 1970s bound up with the world historic process that has come to be known as globalization (Burbach and Robinson, 1999). One process central to capitalist globalization is transnational class formation, which has proceeded in step with the internationalization of capital and the global integration of national productive structures. Given the transnational integration of national economies, the mobility of capital and the global fragmentation and decentralization of accumulation circuits, class formation is progressively less tied to territoriality. The traditional assumption by Marxists that the capitalist class is by theoretical fiat organized in nation-states and driven by the dynamics of national capitalist competition and state rivalries needs to be modified.
We argue in this essay that a transnational capitalist class (henceforth, TCC) has emerged, and that this TCC is a global ruling class. It is a ruling class because it controls the levers of an emergent transnational state apparatus and of global decision making. This TCC is in the process of constructing a new global capitalist historic bloc; a new hegemonic bloc consisting of various economic and political forces that have become the dominant sector of the ruling class throughout the world, among the developed countries of the North as well as the countries of the South. The politics and policies of this ruling bloc are conditioned by the new global structure of accumulation and production. This historic bloc is composed of the transnational corporations and financial institutions, the elite that manage the supranational economic planning agencies, major forces in the dominant political parties, media conglomerates, and technocratic elites and state managers in both North and South.
In what follows, we explore some of the theoretical, conceptual, and empirical issues at stake, although we state as caveat that space constraints preclude a full discussion of these issues. The propositions advanced here are intended to provoke discussion, and as a matter of course are tentative in nature, requiring further substantiation in ongoing research. In part I, we discuss the notion of transnational class formation, identify some of the key developments in the rise of a TCC as agency in the latter decades of the 20th century, and as part and parcel of the same historical process, the rise of a transnational state apparatus in this same period. In part II, we review some empirical data on globalization as indicators of transnational capitalist class formation. Finally, in part III, we discuss the political dynamics of the TCC, including strategic debates and emergent splits among transnational capitalists and their organic intellectuals.
Part I: Transnational Class Formation and the TCC:
Some Conceptual Issues
Since the 1960s a growing number of observers have discussed the rise of an "international capitalist class." In the early 1970s, Stephen Hymer noted that "an international capitalist class is emerging whose interests lie in the world economy as a whole and a system of international private property which allows free movement of capital between countries. ...there is a strong tendency for the most powerful segments of the capitalist class increasingly to see their future in the further growth of the world market rather than its curtailment" (Hymer, 1979:262). Dependency theorists posited the notion of an international bourgeoisie formed out of the alliance of national bourgeoisies bound by their mutual interest in defense of the world capitalist system. In their landmark 1974 study, Global Reach, Barnet and Mueller argued that the spread of multinational corporations had spawned a new international corporate elite. Summarizing much of this earlier work in the 1960s and 1970s, Goldfrank pointed in 1977 to "growing evidence that the owners and managers of multinational enterprises are coming to constitute themselves as a powerful social class" (35), and that "the study of class structure or stratification on a world level is in its infancy (32)."
Parallel to the burgeoning research on economic globalization, studies in more recent years have focused on the process of transnational class formation. Kees van der Pijl's excellent theoretical work on international class formation stands out here (1984; 1989; 1998). He has analyzed the fractionation of capital along functional lines in the post-WWII period in advanced capitalist countries, the internationalization of these fractions and their projects as a consequence of the transnational expansion of capital, and the consequent development of an internationally class consciousness bourgeoisie and of a "comprehensive concept of [bourgeoisie class] control" at the international level. For their part, David Becker and his colleagues, in their controversial thesis on "post-imperialism," observe that global corporations promote the integration of diverse national interests on a new transnational basis. A "corporate international wing" of the managerial bourgeoisie is the prime promoter of this process and the new ruling coalition is comprised of a national "managerial bourgeoisie" of private and public interests in the old Third World and a transnational "corporate bourgeoisie" tied to global corporations. Relatedly, the "Italian School" in international relations has attempted to theorize a global social formation that is increasingly outside the logic of the nation-state (see, esp. Cox, 1987; Gill, 1990). Robert Cox (1987, 271) discusses "an emergent global class structure," and Stephen Gill has identified a "developing transnational capitalist class fraction" (1990, 94). From an entirely different vein, Leslie Sklair's "theory of the global system" (1995) involves the idea of the transnational capitalist class that brings together the executives of transnational corporations, "globalizing bureaucrats, politicians, and professionals", and "consumerist elites" in the media and the commercial sector (1995; 1998). Although his analysis is muddled by a number of theoretical and conceptual confusions, including the conflation of class with strata, and his inability to address the issue of the state, Sklair's work goes the furthest in conceiving of the capitalist class as no longer tied to territoriality or driven by national competition.
What all these accounts share (with the exception of Sklair), is a nation-state centered concept of class. They postulate national bourgeoisies that converge externally with other national classes at the level of the international system through the internationalization of capital and concomitantly, of civil society. World ruling class formation is seen as the international collusion of these national bourgeoisies and their resultant international coalitions. The old view of internationalization as national blocs of capital in competition is merely modified to accommodate collusion in the new globalized age. In contrast, we submit that globalization is establishing the material conditions for the rise of a bourgeoisie whose coordinates are no longer national. In this process of transnational class formation dominant groups fuse into a class (or class fraction) within transnational space. The organic composition, objective position and subjective constitution of these groups are no longer tied to nation-states.
Globalization compels us in this way to modify some of the essential premises of class analysis. An understanding of the changes bound up with globalization requires that our methods and epistemological assumptions revert back to those of classical political economy, which set out to theorize a set of relationships that were not self-evident in contemporary practices in order to highlight both structures and historic movement latent in existing conditions. Marx's generic concept of political economy was general and not in its abstract form coincidental with the nation-state. But as history unfolded in its concrete form the dilemma of political economy became the need to explain the paradox between an economy that was clearly internationalized amidst a world political system that was compartmentalized into separate nation-states. The self-expansion of capital within the territorial boundedness of the nation-state and the international dynamics that resulted from the system of nation-states established the parameters of much social analysis. Those parameters are increasingly unable to capture phenomena bound up with globalization, such as the transnationalization of classes.
From an International to a Transnational Bourgeoisie
Marx and Engels spoke last century in the prescient passages of The Communist Manifesto of the essential global nature of the capitalist system and of the drive of the bourgeoisie to expand its transformative reach around the world. But for Marx, and for many Marxists after him, the bourgeoisie, while it is a global agent, is organically national in the sense that its development takes place within the bounds of specific nation-states and is by fiat a nation-state based class. Early 20th century theories of imperialism established the Marxist analytical framework of rival national capitals, a framework carried by subsequent political economists into the latter 20th century via theories of dependency and the world system, radical international relations theory, studies of U.S. intervention, and so on. Far from sequences of ideas, these theories were developed to explain actual world historic events, such as the two world wars, and to orient practice, such as national revolutions in the Third World seen as directed against particular imperialist countries. The problem was not that these theories stepped outside of history - to the contrary, they were theoretical abstractions from actual historical reality. Rather, they failed to acknowledge the historic specificity of the phenomena they addressed, tending to extrapolate a transhistoric conclusion regarding the dynamics of world class formation from a certain historic period in the development of capitalism.
As a result, in part, of this theoretical and political legacy, much recent research into globalization, by Marxists and non-Marxists alike, has analyzed the process of economic globalization from the political framework of the nation-state system and the agency therein of national classes and groups (for a critique of this "nation-state framework of analysis," see Robinson, 1998; 1999). The classical Marxist view that since capitalism is increasingly international the capitalist class is therefore also international in nature needs to be updated in light of globalization. Inherent in the notion of international is a system of nation-states that mediates relations between classes and groups, including the notion of national capitals and national bourgeoisies. Transnational denotes economic and related social, political, and cultural processes - including class formation - that supersede nation-states. The global economy is bringing shifts in the process of social production worldwide and therefore reorganizing world class structure.
A century ago the rise to economic dominance of the joint stock company and the national corporation had profound effects on the class structure. With the consolidation of national corporations and national markets local and regional capitalists crystallized into national capitalist classes. These became powerful ruling classes that restructured society and ushered in a new era of corporate capitalism. We are in the earlier stages of the same process now replicated at the global level. National capitals have increased fused into transnational capital. The rise of transnational capital out of former national capitals is having a similar transformative effect on what were national capitalist classes. These are drawn by globalization into transnational chains that reorient the determinants of class formation. The leading capitalist strata worldwide are crystallizing into a TCC.
Transnational class formation is therefore a key aspect of the globalization process. Moving one step back in the level of abstraction, globalization involves an "epochal shift" in the development of the world capitalist system (Burbach and Robinson, 1999). Specifically, it represents the transition from the nation-state phase to a new transnational phase of capitalism. In the nation-state phase, the world was linked together via commodity and financial flows in an integrated international market. In the new phase, the worldwide social linkage is an internal one springing from the globalization of the production process itself and the supranational integration of national productive structures, as dicussed below. Globalization therefore redefines the relation between production and territoriality, between nation-states, economic institutions and social structures. Organic class formation is no longer tied to territory and to the political jurisdiction of nation-states.
In the nation-state phase of capitalism, subordinate classes mediated their relation to capital through the nation-state. Capitalist classes developed within the protective cocoon of nation-states and developed interests in opposition to rival national capitals. These states expressed the coalitions of classes and groups that were incorporated into the historic blocs of nation-states. There was nothing transhistoric, or predetermined, about this process of class formation worldwide. It is now being superseded by globalization. The global decentralization and fragmentation of the production process redefines the accumulation of capital, and classes, in relation to the nation-state. What is occurring is a process of transnational class formation, in which the mediating element of national states has been modified. Social groups, both dominant and subordinate, have been globalizing through the structures, institutions, and phenomenology of a nation-state world, the atavistic historical infrastructure upon which capitalism is building a new transnational institutionality.
The nation-state is no longer the organizing principle of capitalism and the institutional "container" of class development and social life. As national productive structures now become transnationally integrated, world classes whose organic development took place through the nation-state are experiencing supra-national integration with "national" classes of other countries. Global class formation has involved the accelerated division of the world into a global bourgeoisie and a global proletariat, and has brought changes in the relationship between dominant and subordinate classes, with consequent implications as well for world politics. The world politics of the TCC is not driven, as they were for national capitalist classes, by the flux of shifting rivalries and alliances played out through the interstate system, as we discuss later on.
The reality of capital as a totality of competing individual capitals and their concrete existence as a class relation within specific spatial confines determined geographically as nation-states worked against a trans-, or supranational, unifying trend in the development of world capitalism. The liberation of capital from such spatial barriers brought about by new technologies, the worldwide reorganization of production, and the lifting of nation-state constraints to the operation of the global market taking place under globalization imply that the locus of class and group relations in the current period is not the nation-state. Yet many Marxists and non-Marxists alike advance a peculiar dualist construct that posits separate logics for a globalizing economic and a nation-state based political system. The nation-state is seen in this dualist construct as immanent to capitalist development, and transnational class formation therefore cannot really be conceived beyond the class and collusion of "national" classes.
But such a dualist construct flies in the face of the fundamental tenets of historical materialism, if we are to maintain that material conditions, and in particular the process of production, are central to political development and that classes are grounded in real economic production relations. If we acknowledge that these production relations are globalizing then it is incumbent upon us to address the issue of transnational class formation. Let us therefore focus briefly on the matter of the globalization of production before returning to the TCC.
The Globalization of Production and the Circuit of Capital
Global capitalism is not the mere collection of "national economies," as the dominant conception would suggest (see, inter-alia, Wood, 1999). Many critics who argue that globalization is overstated, or even illusory (E.g., Wood, 1999; Gordon, 1988; Hirst and Thomas, 1996; Weiss, 1998; Glyn and Sutcliff, 1992), claim that the current period is merely a quantitative intensification of historical tendencies and not a qualitatively new epoch. But this argument does not distinguish between the extension of trade and financial flows across national borders, which in our conception represents internationalization, and the globalization of the production process itself, which represents transnationalization. These accounts point to the high degree of world trade integration in the period prior to World War I (indeed, the world economy was at that time at least as integrated economically as it is at the beginning of the 21st century). But they fail to note what is qualitatively new. The pre-1913 integration was through "arms-length" trade in goods and services between nationally-based production systems and through cross border financial flows in the form of portfolio capital. In this period national capitalist classes organized national production chains and produced commodities within their own borders (actually, labor produced those commodities) which they then traded for commodities produced in other countries. This is what Dicken calls "shallow integration" (1998:5). It is in contrast to "deep integration" taking place under globalization. This involves the transnationalization of the production of goods and services.
The globalization of production has entailed the fragmentation and decentralization of complex production chains and the worldwide dispersal and functional integration of the different segments in these chains. This globalization of production has been increasingly researched. What concerns us here is its social and political implications, in particular, as regards class formation. It is the globalization of production that provides the basis for the transnationalization of classes and the rise of a TCC. In his important works on the internationalization of capital, Christian Palloix has suggested a clear historic sequence: the circuit of commodity capital was the first to become internationalized in the form of world trade; the circuit of money capital was the second, in the form of the flow of portfolio investment capital into overseas ventures; the circuits of productive capital is the most recent, in the form of the massive growth of TNCs in the post-WWII period (Palloix, 1977a; 1977b).
This transnationalization of production has expanded dramatically since Palloix wrote in the late 1970s, involving not merely the spread of TNC activities, but the restructuring, fragmentation, and worldwide decentralization of the production process (see, inter-alia, Dicken, 1998; Howells and Wood, 1992; Burbach and Robinson, 1999; UNCTAD, various years). Let us recall the centrality of the circuit of capital to class analysis, and that this circuit is embedded in social, political, and cultural processes. It is around the circuit, particularly M-C-P-C'-M' (including, crucially, P, or production) that class formation takes place, classes struggle, political processes unfold, states attempt to create the general conditions for the circuit's reproduction, cultural processes spring forth, and so on. In the earlier period of "shallow integration," the first part of this circuit, M-C-P-C', took place in national economies. Commodities were sold on the international market, and profits returned home, where the cycle was repeated. Under globalization P is increasingly globally decentralized, and so too is the entire first part of the circuit, M-C-P. Globally produced goods and services are marketed worldwide. Profits are dispersed worldwide through the global financial system that has emerged since the 1980s and which is qualitatively different from the international financial flows of the earlier period. As the entire circuit becomes transnationalized, so too do classes, political processes, states, and cultural-ideological processes. What is of concern in the present essay is transnational class formation and the rise of a TCC. Transnationalization of the capital circuit implies as well the transnationalization of the agents of capital. As national circuits of capital become transnationally integrated, these new transnational circuits become the sites of class formation worldwide.
Those who argue that globalization is merely a quantitative deepening of the process of internationalization also point to the continued existence of nation-state phenomena, such as national variations and "distinctiveness," certain production processes which are clearly contained within the bounds of particular nation-states, national capitalist groupings and their political protagonism and even state practices in countries where these groups are able to influence those practices, continued inter-state rivalries, the lingering phenomenology of the nation-state, and so on (see, inter-alia, Wood, 1999). All of these phenomena are currently present, yet they by no means invalidate the analysis of globalization as a qualitatively new epoch in the development of world capitalism. There is absolutely nothing in the conception and the method of dialectical analysis and of historical materialism to suggest that contradictory phenomena cannot coexist, as we discuss below in the concrete case of national and transnational class fractions and the contradictions between them. Within the totality of historic structures there are numerous processes that are in contradiction with one another or moving in separate directions within a larger unity. Globalization is a process, not a state or a condition. It is a conception of historic structure in motion, and as such numerous forms may be involved in its dynamics, such as ascendant transnational and descendant nation-state forms of class, of productive structure, and so on. What is important for materialist analysis is to capture the direction of historic movement and the tendencies underway, even when such historic processes are open-ended, subject to being pushed in new and unforseen directions, and even to reversals.
The TCC as a Class-in-Itself and a Class-for-Itself
By class, we mean a group of people who share a common relationship to the process of social production and reproduction and which are constituted relationally on the basis of social power struggles. The concept can apply to antagonistic polar opposites, such as the bourgeoisie and the proletariat, and also to fractional interests within a single class (e.g., industrial and commercial capital). A dialectic analysis of transnational class formation must start with the primacy of social relations of production in the constitution of antagonistic classes, and with the derivation of specific classes or class fractions, such as a TCC, from class struggle grounded in these relations. Marx and Engels clearly identified class as a collective position vis-a-vis the means of production and the production process. But they also suggested that the existence of a class was conditional upon its capacity to forge a collective political and/or cultural protagonism, that is, a self-representation, and that class formation involves the mutual constitution of antagonistic classes. This dialectic conception is best captured in Marx's notion of a class-in-itself and a class-for-itself, and epitomized in the modern literature on class perhaps above all in the works of E.P. Thompson.
The study of class formation therefore involves structural and agency levels of analysis. The first is concerned with the material bases and the production relations which give rise to and define classes; the second, with intentionality and with the forms of consciousness involved in intervention that shape social processes and as well the direction of development in material relations. At the level of structure, the global economy, specifically the transnationalization of capital, provides the material basis for a TCC. The TCC can be located in the global class structure by its ownership and/or control of transnational capital. Transnational capital constitutes the "commanding heights" of the global economy, that fraction of capital that imposes the general direction and character on production worldwide and conditions the social, political, and cultural character of capitalist society worldwide. The members of the TCC are the owners of the major productive resources of the world, or, as Marx expressed it, "the owners of the system of production."
We argue thus that the TCC is that segment of the world bourgeoisie that represents transnational capital. The old international alliance of national bourgeoisies has mutated into a transnational bourgeoisie in the new epoch, and this transnational bourgeoisie has become the hegemonic class fraction globally. Here fraction denotes segments within classes determined by their relation to social production and the class as a whole. This TCC is comprised of the owners of transnational capital, that is, the group that owns the leading worldwide means of production as embodied principally in the transnational corporations and private financial institutions. What distinguishes the TCC from national or local capitalists is that it is involved in globalized production and manages globalized circuits of accumulation that give it an objective class existence and identity spatially and politically in the global system above any local territories and polities.
At the level of agency, the TCC is class conscious, has become conscious of its transnationality, and has been pursuing a class project of capitalist globalization, as reflected in its global decision-making and the rise of a transnational state apparatus under the auspices of this fraction. The proletariat worldwide is as well in the process of transnational class formation. A transnational working class is increasingly a reality, a class-in-itself. But it is not yet for-itself for reasons bound up with the continued existence of the nation-state and uneven development that we cannot explore here. The TCC, however, is increasingly a class-in-itself and for-itself. Capitalist globalization has, in the momentary historical juncture of the late 20th and early 21st century, increased the relative power of global capital over global labor by acting as a centripetal force for the capitalist class and as a centrifugal force for the working class.
Globalization, Transnational Class Fractionation, and the TCC
Class fractionation is occurring along a new national/transnational axis. In recent years, in every country of the world, transnationalized fractions, or nuclei, of local dominant groups have emerged. Here contradictory logics of national and global accumulation are at work. The interests of one group lies in national accumulation, including the whole set of traditional national regulatory and protectionist mechanisms, and the other in an expanding global economy based on worldwide market liberalization. The struggle between descendant national fractions of dominant groups and ascendant transnational fractions has often been the backdrop to surface political dynamics and ideological processes in the late 20th century.
These two fractions have been vying for control of local state apparatuses since the 1970s. Transnational fractions of local elites swept to power in countries around the world in the 1980s and 1990s. They have captured the "commanding heights" of state policymaking - key ministries and bureaucracies in the policymaking apparatus, especially, Central Banks, finance and foreign ministries, as key government branches which link countries to the global economy. They have utilized national state apparatuses to advance globalization and to pursue sweeping economic restructuring, the dismantling of the old nation-state based Keynesian welfare and developmentalist projects. They have sought world-wide market liberalization (including the neo-liberal model), projects of economic integration such as the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), the Asia Pacific Economic Cooperation (APEC) forum, and the European Union; and they promoted a supra-national infrastructure of the global economy, such as the World Trade Organization, as we discuss below.
One key question with regard to national/transnational fractionation is the relationship between globalization and the traditional fractionation of capital into industrial, commercial, and financial groups. The national/transnational axis is a second dividing line, superimposed on traditional capital fractionation. Finance capital has certainly become hegemonic. It is the most mobile and the most deterritorialized. Some $25 trillion in currency is moved daily in global financial markets, and the daily turnover at the largest stock markets has surpassed $1 trillion (Harris, 1998/99:23), compared to a daily world trade of only about $10 billion (so that real trade is only 1 percent of fictitious trade). In the 1970s and 1980s finance capital came to determine circuits of global accumulation, that is, money capital becomes the regulator of the international circuit of production rather than investment capital. Transnational banks and investment firms, as well as Central Banks, hold vast foreign currencies and utilizes diverse currencies for their worldwide transactions. Under such circumstances it would be difficult to argue that world political dynamics are shaped by struggles for dollar, yen, or some other currency's hegemony, as they were in for instance the pre-1913 period, or in earlier moments in the post-WWII period. The TCC and different national states have a vested interest in a stable global monetary system.
What accounts for these dramatic developments in the world financial system, and the apparent decoupling of financial from productive capital, phenomena without precedent, has been hotly debated. Clearly it is linked to technological change and the possibilities opened up by informatics. It is probably also linked to cycles in world capitalism, in particular the Kondratieff cycles, in that the end of long swings (e.g., of the post-WWII boom) is characterized by an abundance of capital savings and accumulated surplus value expressed in the hegemony of money capital and financial speculation (Arrighi, 1994). But for the purposes of analysis of the TCC what is important is that the globalization process affects productive and commercial capital, and therefore it cannot be argued that class fractionation in the age of globalization is between mobile money capital on the one hand, and "fixed" productive capital on the other (with commercial capital somewhere in between).
In fact, the national/transnational axis cuts across money, commercial, and productive capital, such that all three are split internally along the axis (see, e.g., van der Pijl, 53). Also relevant, but not possible to take up here, is Hilferding's notion of finance capital as the socialization of money, commercial, and industrial capital into an interdependent complex. To what extent has transnational capital organically fractionalized? Or in fact does it constitute transnational finance capital in Hilferding's sense? We would speculate, given the interlocking structures of transnational corporations and banks (see, e.g., Fennema, 1982; van der Pijl, 1998, esp. chapter 2) that the latter is the case and that differences among transnational capitals are therefore strategic and between conglomerates. Finally, it is worth noting that most transnational units of production are simultaneously involved directly or indirectly in financial, productive, and commercial capital operations and investment.
The rise of a TCC therefore involves more integrated global capitals and we best examine the phenomenon of global class formation from angles other than traditional class analysis of fractions, such as from that of local versus global accumulation circuits and from national or territorial-bound versus transnational or deterritorialized class interests. Van der Pijl has argued that money interests have tended to manifest themselves in liberalism and cosmopolitanism, whereas productive capital has manifested itself historically in planning locally and nationally, and hence transnationalization has been led by money capital (1984; 1989). This might have been so in earlier epochs of capitalism but clearly central to globalization has been the fragmentation and global decentralization and dispersal of production, made possible in part by a new generation of science and technology and entailing the tendency towards the dissolution of "fixity" in productive capital. As has been amply documented, many previously nationally-based industries, such as autos, electronics, textiles, and computers, and even, in fact, services, are now thoroughly transnationalized (see, e.g., Dicken, 1998; Howells and Wood, 1992; UNCTAD, various years). Moreover, money capital must "land" in production, which under globalization is increasingly impermanent and dispersed in mobile worldwide production sites exhibiting accelerated turnover (and hence decreased fixity) time.
The Formation of a Transnational State Apparatus
The TCC is dominant economically, but is it also dominant politically and culturally? In what sense and in what degree can the TCC be shown to be a global ruling class? Does the TCC act collectively as a class in the exercise of political power? The economically dominant class is not necessarily the ruling class; that it is (or is not) is something that must be demonstrated. Here we proceed in order of determination from economic dominance to political rule. We draw out our earlier proposition that a transnational capitalist class as a class fraction of the world bourgeoisie has emerged, and that this TCC is in the process of achieving its rule or becoming a global ruling class. The TCC has articulated economic interests with political aims in pursuing the globalist project of an integrated global economy and society, what elsewhere Robinson has referred to as the "transnational elite agenda" aimed at creating the conditions most propitious to the unfettered functioning of global capitalism (Robinson, 1996a; 1996b; 1997; 1998/99; 1999).
It is not possible, therefore, to provide a comprehensive picture of the TCC without reference to its objective determinants in the productive structure - and here the transnationalization of the production process is key - and also with reference to its subjective determination - and here the rise of a transnational state (TNS) apparatus as a crucial political and institutional expression of the TCC is important. In other words, analysis of the power of the capitalist ruling class cannot be separated from the issue of the state and the political process. But we can proceed in order of determination to analyze, first, the economic-material determination of the TCC as embodied in transnational capital, and second, the exercise of its class power as expressed in TNS apparatuses. In other words, social power as domination is embodied in wealth (the means of production and the social product) and exercised through institutions (especially the state).
The dialectic of structure and agency has driven the process of globalization. Globalization is an objective process insofar as it is a consequence, not a cause, of the dynamics of capitalist development and a stage in the centuries-long expansion of world capitalism. And it is a subjective process insofar as it is unfolding as the result of agency. Dominant groups and especially the TCC, have sought transnationalization as a means of resolving problems of accumulation. And the political protagonism and class struggle of subordinate classes at the level of the national state and the constraints it placed on capital at that level is what first drove capital to transnationalize. We should recall that a dominant class exercises its rule through political institutions whose higher personnel must represent the class, unifying so far as possible its actions and reinforcing its control over the process of social reproduction, which in this case means ensuring the reproduction of global capitalist relations of production and at the same time the reproduction (or transformation) of political and cultural institutions favorable to its rule.
The leading strata among the emergent TCC became politicized from the 1970s into the 1990s. The notion of a managerial elite at the apex of the global ruling class which controls the levers of global policymaking captures the idea of a politically active wing of the global ruling class. As part of its political protagonism, this wing set about to create and/or transform a set of emerging transnational institutions. These institutions constitute an incipient TNS apparatus in formation. This TNS apparatus is an emerging network that comprises transformed and externally-integrated national states, together with the supranational economic and political forums and that has not yet acquired any centralized institutional form. The economic forums include the International Monetary Fund (IMF), the World Bank, the World Trade Organization (WTO), the regional banks, and so on. The political forums include the Group of 7 and the recently formed Group of 22, among others, as well as the United Nations system, the Organization of Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), the European Union, the Conference on Security and Cooperation in Europe (CSCE), and so on. The TCC has directly instrumentalized this TNS apparatus, exercising a form of transnational state power through the multilayered configuration of the TNS. It is through these global institutions that the TCC has been attempting to forge a new global capitalist hegemonic bloc.
As transnational corporate and political elites emerged on the world scene in the 1980s they made explicit claims to building and managing a global economy through restructured multilateral and national institutions. The political organization of the TCC included the formation in the mid-1970s of the Trilateral Commission, which brought together transnationalized fractions of the business, political, and intellectual elite in North America, Europe, and Japan (Gill, 1990). Others markers in its politicization were: the creation of the Group of 7 forum at the governmental level, which began institutionalizing collective management of the global economy by corporate and political elites from core nation-states; the expansion of the activities of the OECD, formed as a supranational institution by the 24 largest industrialized countries to observe and coordinate their national economies; and the creation of the World Economic Forum (WEF), which brought together the top representatives of transnational corporations and global political elites (see below). Studies on building a global economy and transnational management structures flowed out of think tanks, university centers, and policy planning institutes in core countries.
This increasingly organized global elite articulated a coherent program of global economic and political restructuring centered around market liberalization - the so-called "Washington consensus" (Williamson, 1993), or the neo-liberal project (see below) - and set out to convert the world into a single unified field for global capitalism. It pushed for greater uniformity and standardization in the codes and rules of the global market - a process similar to the construction of national markets in the 19th century but now replicated in the new global space. The G-7 in 1982 designated the IMF and the World Bank as the central authorities for exercising the collective power of the capitalist national states over international financial negotiations (Harvey, 1990, 170). At the Cancun Summit in Mexico in 1982, the core capitalist states, led by the United States, launched the era of global neo-liberalism as part of this process and began imposing structural adjustment programs on the Third World and the then-Second World. Transnational elites promoted international economic integration processes, created new sets of institutions and forums, such as the WTO, the Multilateral Agreement on Investment (MAI), and so on. The institutions of this TNS such as the IMF, the World Bank, and WTO are not merely instruments of a world bourgeoisie against world labor; they are also instruments of some fractions of capital against others. They are not neutral vis-a-vis the different capitalist fractions. They suppress national fractions, opposing solutions (e.g., protectionism, fixed exchange rates, etc.) that would bolster national capitals and promote the interests of transnational fractions.
The TNS has been one important forum of transnational class socialization, as have world class universities, transnationally-oriented think tanks, the leading bourgeois foundations, such as Harvard's School of International Business, the Ford and the Carnegie Foundations, policy planning groups such as the Council on Foreign Relations, and so on. Elite planning groups are important forums for integrating class groups, developing new initiatives, collective strategies, policies and projects of class rule, and forging consensus and a political culture around these projects. Since at least late last century the corporate elite has operated through political organizations. These peak business associations function as bodies that connect capital with other spheres (governments, organs of civil society, cultural forums, etc.) at numerous levels. These have included in the United States, for instance, the Business Roundtable, the Chamber of Commerce, and the National Association of Manufacturers, among others. In recent years, there has been a veritable proliferation of transnationally-oriented capitalist organizations and planning groups beyond such better known ones as the Trilateral Commission. For instance, the Institute of International Finance (IIF) was created in 1983 by representatives from transnational banks and investment firms and has 300 members in 56 countries around the world. The IIF acts as a policy center, lobbyist, researcher and consultant for its membership, a virtual political center for transnational finance.
But it is the World Economic Forum (WEF) that stands out as the most comprehensive transnational planning body of the TCC and the quintessential example of a truly global network binding together the TCC in a transnational civil society. As van der Pijl notes, the WEF's component bodies are all acknowledged class organizations, in the sense of being subject to "strict conditions of admission in order to preserve their peer character" (1998:133). These different component bodies include: the CEO's of the top 1,000 TNCs (this component body is known as "Foundation Members" and is the core of the WEF); representatives from 100 of the most influential media groups worldwide ("World Media Leaders"); key policymakers from national governments around the world and from international organizations ("World Economic Leaders"); select academics and experts from political, economic, scientific, social and technological fields ("Forum Fellows"); and so on. "A body of this scope clearly has not existed every before," observers van der Pijl. "It is a true International of capital" (1998:133).
Global media has also been a crucial medium in the socialization of the TCC and in the development of its hegemonic project. The ownership and merger of media worldwide is a major area of transnationalization. Beyond the economic implications of the transnational corporate media and its tight control over the worldwide flow of information and of images are issues of cultural domination. The global corporate media plays an essential role in producing the ideological and cultural bases for a hegemonic bloc that brings together the TCC with other classes, groups, and strata. This transnational socialization of the TCC is crucial to the extent that class formation is as much a subjective as an objective process, and is complemented by the creation of transnational "epistemic communities" of organic intellectuals. Social scientists have long noted the role of cultural, educational and other mechanisms that generate the cohesion necessary for a class to bind together and to reproduce itself (e.g, the works of Domhoff, Useem, Dye, and Mills). The process of transnational socialization, including and emergent TNS as an organic representation of the TCC, transnational capitalist forums, the role of the media, and so on, needs to be studied further.
Despite its organization and coherence, the transnational bourgeoisie is not a unified group. "The same conditions, the same contradiction, the same interests necessarily called forth on the whole similar customs everywhere," noted Marx and Engels in discussing the formation of new class groups. "But separate individuals form a class only insofar as they have to carry on a common battle against another class; otherwise they are on hostile terms with each other as competitors" (Marx and Engels, 1970:82). Fierce competition among oligopolist clusters, conflicting pressures, and differences over the tactics and strategy of maintaining class domination and addressing the crises and contradictions of global capitalism make any real internal unity in the global ruling class impossible. We retake this issue below.
Part II: Some Empirical Indicators of
Transnational Capitalist Class Formation
Are capitalists transnational only in the sense that they span the globe with their economic power, or are they transnational in the sense that they are beginning to merge as a global bourgeoisie through corporate mergers, banking interests, and so on? We suggest that the former situation is an indicator of an international bourgeoisie while the latter are indicators of a transnational bourgeoisie. Internationalization occurs when national capitals expand their reach beyond their own national borders. Transnationalization is when national capitals fuse with other internationalizing national capitals in a process that disembedds them from their nations and locates them in new supranational space opening up under the global economy.
The boundaries of the TCC are indeterminate. At what point national classes become transformed into transnational classes is open to debate - despite the fact that we can conceptually distinguish such a class - and depends upon the devices we construct to define the material bases of transnational classes. Empirical evidence on the rise of the TCC includes the spread of transnational corporations (TNCs), the expansion of direct foreign investment, cross-national mergers, strategic alliances, the interpenetration of capital, and interlocking directorates that are transnational. As well are the phenomena of worldwide subcontracting and outsourcing, the extension of free enterprise zones, and a number of other new economic forms associated with the global economy. Such new forms of organizing globalized production are important because they contribute to the development of worldwide networks that link local capitalists to one another, generate an identity of objective interests and of subjective outlook among these capitalists around a process of global (as opposed to local) accumulation. They therefore function as integrative mechanisms in the formation of the TCC and act to shift the locus of class formation from national to emergent transnational space. Here we provide a cursory glance at some of these indicators. The objective is to provide some empirical references points for our theoretical exposition, in conjunction with the conjunctural analysis in the next section, and to the point the way for future research on the TCC, which requires a systematic study of such data not possible here.
A key indicator of the rise of the TCC and its agents is the spread of TNCs. TNCs embody the transnationalized circuits of capital and organize those circuits. In 1995, according to the UNCTAD (1996:3), there were some 40,000 companies with headquarters in more than three countries and some two-thirds of world trade was carried out by TNCs. Similarly, the share of world GDP controlled by TNCs grew from 17 percent in the mid-1960s to 24 percent in 1984 and almost 33 percent in 1995 (ibid.). Perhaps the single most comprehensive indicator of TNC activity and the growth of transnational production is the global stock of foreign direct investment (FDI, see Table 1), which was valued at over $4 trillion, with its rate of growth over the previous decade more than double that of gross fixed capital formation throughout the world. In 1994 it is estimated that the worldwide assets of corporate foreign affiliates was $8.4 trillion. Local firms become incorporated into the transnational corporate structure through an array of mechanisms involved in FDI and TNC activity, ranging from mergers, contracting and outsourcing arrangements, local marketing deals, take-overs, and so on. And as of 1995, some 280,000 affiliates of transnational corporations produced goods and services estimated at $7 trillion (UNCTAD, 1996:xv-xvi).
Until the 1980s, most merger and acquisition activity occurred within national boundaries, but within the last two decades cross-border acquisitions and mergers have become one of the most important ways for firms to expand their activities transnationally (Dicken, 1998:222) and are an essential mechanism in the transnationalization process. The concentration of capital is not new. It is part of the very process of capitalist development and was an integral aspect in an earlier period of national class formation and the rise of national bourgeosies. The transnational concentration of capital through global mergers and acquisitions has a similar importance for transnational class formation and the rise of a transnational bourgeoisie. Some of cross-border acquisitions involves the merger of TNCs, but much of it entails the acquisition of national companies by TNCs, which draws local social forces into the transnationalization process.
Of the $589 billion in total global FDI outflows in 1997, $342 billion, or 58 percent of the total, went into mergers and acquisitions. This means that just about two-fifths of FDI was in new or start up investments: the remainder was used to buy up other companies across national borders. In the case of mergers, it meant the integration of capitals from at least two distinct countries. If an acquisition, it meant that a given firm incorporated a foreign company with its employees, managers, and "national" interests. Summarizing the current "merger mania," Business Week noted: "In industries ranging from autos to telecoms, analysts predict the merger craze will continue" (1998b:53). Cross-border mergers and acquisitions have involved not just the most globalized sectors of the world economy, such as telecommunications, finances, and autos, but also mega-retailers, companies trading in primary commodities, chemicals, and numerous services, from legal firms to insurance and management. Some of the largest cross-national mergers and acquisition in recent years have been: the record-breaking merger of British Telecom and MCI (telecommunications); Daimler Benz and Crystler (autos); Dupont and Herberts (chemicals and paints); Alcatel and Motorola (phone and telecommunications equipment), and Alcatel's subsequent acquisition of DSC Communications; the acquisition of MCA by Seagram (entertainment); and the purchase of Marion Merrel Dow by Hoeschst (phareceuticals) [UNCTAD, 1996:12]. In the first nine months of 1998, such transnational merger and acquisition deals across the world totalled $383 billion, more than the total for 1997. As this process deepens transnational capital gains increasing control over every sector of the global economy and transnational class formation accelerates. Commenting on the wave of global mergers during an interview in which he announced the takeover of Random House by Berttelsman, Thomas Middelhoff, Berttelsman's Chair,noted: "There are no German and American companies. There are only successful and unsuccessful companies" (White, 1998:1).
TABLE 1: GLOBAL FDI OUTFLOWS, 1983-1997
In Billions of Dollars and Percentage Growth Rate
(Average Annual Amount and Growth Rates for Batch Years 1983-1987 and 1988-1992)
------------------------------------------------
Year Amount % Growth
1983-1987 76.8 35
1988-1992 208.5 4
1993 225.5 11
1994 230.0 2
1995 317.8 38
1996 347 9
1997 589 41
1998 644 39
-------------------------------------------------
SOURCE: As reported by: UNCTAD World Investment Reports, 1996, pp. 4; UNCTAD, 1997, pp. 4. 1997 figure from UNCTAD 1998 report, pp. 19. 1998 figures from UNCTAD 1998 report, as reported The Economist, June 26, 1999:7.
Importantly, there has been a high degree of cross-investment between the major capitalist countries (Dicken, 1998:45-46), which indicates a high degree of interpenetration of "national" capitals in the process of FDI expansion. The developing world absorbed four-fifths of pre-WWII FDI through the old colonial "spheres of influence" structure of world order. But most FDI flows from the 1960s into the 1980s took place between core regions. This is important because the first pattern of FDI reflects a situation in which core national bourgeoisies were in rivalry, whereas the latter indicates a key mechanism in the transnationalization of these of these "national" bourgeoisies. It is in the Third World where transnational class formation is weakest and where "national" bourgeosies may still control states and organize influential political projects. However, even here transnational class formation is well underway. In a recent report, the ILO noted that FDI has "increased sharply, especially to developing countries. The average annual flows have increased more than three-fold since the early 1980s for the world as a whole, while for developing countries it had increased fivefold by 1993" (ILO, 1996-97:2). National capitals in the South have themselves increasingly transnationalized by their own FDI and by integrating into global circuits of accumulation. In 1960, only one percent of FDI came from developing countries. By 1985, this figure had increased to around 3 percent, and by 1995 it stood at about 8 percent (Dicken, 1998:44). Southern-based TNCs have invested $51 billion abroad, while developing countries have absorbed an increasingly proportion of FDI in the 1990s (Burbach and Robinson, 1999). The Third World bourgeoisie of countries such as Singapore, South Korea, Taiwan, Brazil, Chile, and Mexico are becoming important "national" contingents of the TCC (see Ibid.) In 1996 for the first time two third world companies, Daewoo Corporation of South Korea and Petroleos de Venezuela joined the ranks of the top 100 transnational corporations. The top 50 TNCs of the Third World augmented their foreign assets by 280 percent between 1993 and 1995, while those of the top 100 corporations based in the core countries increased by only 30% (ILO, 1996:xvii).
Another important aspect of the transnationalization of Third World economies is the growing importance of foreign portfolio equity investments (FPEI), which are not counted as FDI flows. These are international investments mainly by stock brokerage firms and mutual funds in foreign stock markets managing the capital of investors generally interested only in securing an ample return on their investments and exercise virtually no direct role in the company in which they invest. FPEI flows therefore represent a pronounced transnationalization of capital in that they are carried out by an array of investors with origins in a large number of countries. Many Third World countries in the 1990s as part of the drive to implement neo-liberal, free market policies have facilitated FPEI inflows by establishing or liberalizing their stock market exchanges. Referred to as "emerging markets," these represent a dramatic transnationalization of national firms and assets that accelerates the formation of the TCC.
The growth of direct and equity investment flows are part of the dramatic and growing integration of world capital markets through the commodification of financial instruments. One study found that the total market value of securities traded in world capital markets tripled between 1980 and 1992 (Akdogan, 1995:9). The same study revealed that international gross equity flows doubled between 1986 and 1989, and that in 1991 they were equal to more than one quarter of the capital in the world capital markets. Aside from equity investments, other components of world capital markets are bond and debt financing as well as derivatives, stock options, warrants and convertibles. The rise of a new globally-integrated financial system since the 1980s has been truly phenomenal. National stock markets have all but disappeared. Between 1980 and 1990 the volume of cross-border transactions in equities alone grew at a compound rate of 28 percent per year, from $120 billion to $1.4 trillion. The stock of cross-border bank lending rose from $324 billion to $7.5 trillion over the same period, and offshore bond markets (where companies issue "I owe yous" offshore), increased by 537 percent, from $259 billion to $1.6 trillion. As Hoogvelt notes, if we add up all these categories of world financial integration plus the stock of principal derivatives and FDI, "the total exceeds the total of the combined FDI of the OECD economies" (Hoogvelt, 1997:78-80).
Transnationalization is reflected as well in ever-greater trade integration. World trade has grown much faster than output, and this growth, after slowing briefly in the early 1990s, a consequence of the worldwide downturn, picked up again in mid-decade, as the following table indicates:
TABLE 2: GROWTH OF WORLD TRADE (GOODS AND SERVICES) AND GROWTH OF REAL GDP, 1974-1995
----------------------------------------------------------------
World Trade World GDP
(Growth in Volume) (Percentage, Annual Average)
1974-83: 3.1 1974-80: 3.4
1984-89: 6.4 1981-90: 3.2
1990-93: 4.6 1991-93: 1.2
1994: 8.7 1994: 2.9
1995: 7.9 1995: 2.8
----------------------------------------------------------------
SOURCE: ILO (1997:3)
World trade can indicate internationalization and not transnationalization. But once we note that between one-third and two-thirds of this world trade is conducted as intra-firm trade (World Bank, 1992, 22) it becomes clear that data on the growth of world trade is itself a commercial expression of globalized production. The ILO report emphasizes: "These increased flows of direct investment have been accompanied by the growth of globally-integrated production systems characterized by the rapid expansion of intra-firm trade in intermediate products and of subcontracting, licensing and franchising arrangements, including new forms of outsourcing of work across national frontiers" (ILO, 1996-97:2).
This phenomenal spread since the late 1970s of diverse new economic arrangements, such as outsourcing, subcontracting, transnational intercorporate alliances, licensing agreements, local representation, and so on, parallels the proliferation of FDI, mergers and acquisitions, and underscores another major aspect of the transnational linkage of capitals. These arrangements result in vast transnational production chains and complex webs of vertical and horizontal integration across the globe. According to Dicken:
TNCs are also locked into external networks of relationships with a myriad of other firms: transnational and domestic, large and small, public and private. It is through such interconnections, for example, that a very small firm in one country may be directly linked into a global production network, whereas most small firms serve only a very restricted geographic area. Such inter-relationships between firms of different sizes and types increasingly span national boundaries to create a set of geographically nested relationships from local to global scales....There is, in fact, a bewildering variety of interorganizational collaborative relationships. These are frequently multilateral rather than bilateral, polygamous rather than monogamous (Dicken, 1998:223)
What Dicken's authoritive study underscores is the increasing interpenetration on multiple levels of capitals in all parts of the world, organized around transnational capital and the giant TNCs. It is increasingly difficult to separate local circuits of production and distribution from the globalized circuits that dictate the terms and patterns of accumulation worldwide, even when surface appearance gives the (misleading) impression that local capitals retain their autonomy. There are of course still local and national capitals, and there will be for a long time to come. But they must "de-localize" and link to hegemonic transnational capital if they are to survive. Territorially restricted capital cannot compete with its transnationally-mobile counterpart. As the global circuit of capital subsumes through numerous mechanisms and arrangements these local circuits, local capitalists who manage these circuits become swept up into the process of transnational class formation.
The diverse new economic arrangements in the global economy have been associated with the transition from the Fordist regime of accumulation to new post-Fordist flexible regimes (see, inter-alia, Harvey, 1990; Amin, 1994; Hoogvelt, 1997; Dicken, 1998). As many have noted, the structural properties of the emerging flexible regime are global in character, in that accumulation is embedded in global markets, involves global enterprise organization and sets of global capital-labor relations (especially deregulated and casualized labor pools worldwide) [see, inter-alia, Hoogvelt, 1997:109-113]. Competition dictates that firms must establish global as opposed to national or regional markets. As Hoogvelt shows, competition in the global economy increasingly compels them to operate full production systems in all three regions of the global triad (North America, Europe, and East Asia). The leading TNCs are becoming "multi-regional" companies, operating multiple and integrated production as well as financial and commercial operations throughout the triad (ibid). These multi-regional companies are emerging through the strategy of alliances, mergers, and other forms of integrative coordination among TNCs, as a general transitionary form in the process of the transnational integration of capital.
Meanwhile, each shock in the unfolding world economic crisis, from Mexico to Asia, from Russia to Brazil, has tended to result in an accelerated transnational integration of affected countries of local capitalists into the ranks of the TCC. These crises clearly bring into sharper relief the process of fractionation among local elites. For instance, the Asian crisis is leading to a restructuring of many of the region's major corporations and economies that facilitates and advances the consolidation of transnational capital. The "chaebol," the powerful financial-industrial groups of South Korea, for instance, have been compelled to sell off national assets to TNCs and at the same time they have forged partnerships with corporations from other areas of the world (Business Week, 1998a). As Lawrence Summers stated in 1998 when he was undersecretary of the U.S. Treasury Department, "In some ways the IMF has done more in these past months to liberalize these [Asian] economies and open up their markets to U.S. goods and services than has been achieved in rounds of negotiations in the region" (cited in Bello, 1998/99:138).
Increasingly, the leading strata among the TCC has come to occupy a variety of interlocking positions within the global corporate structure. Fennema, for instance, identified for the early 1980s an international network of interlocking directorates among the leading transnational banking and industrial firms (1982). This process parallels a similar one in an earlier period, when the rise of national bourgeoisies involved national-level interlocking directorates that congealed the objective links and the subjective identity of national bourgeoisies, as documented in a wealth of literature, Marxist and non-Marxist, from political sociology on the subject of national "power elites", and ruling blocs, the "inner circle", and so on (see, inter alia, Domhoff, 1967; Useem, 1984; Dye, 1986; Mills, 1959). The evolving composition of the directorates of the leading TNCs is an area ripe for research.
Part III: Hegemony and the
Global Politics "From Above" of the TCC
The new global ruling bloc consists of various economic and political forces led by the TCC whose politics and policies are conditioned by the new global structure of accumulation and production. It is the logic of global accumulation, rather than national accumulation, that guides the political and economic behavior of this ruling bloc, henceforth referred to as the "globalist" bloc. At the center of the globalist bloc is the TCC, comprised of the owners and managers of the transnational corporations and other capitalists around the world who manage transnational capital. The bloc also includes the cadre, bureaucratic managers and technicians who administer the agencies of the TNS, such as the IMF, the World Bank, and the WTO, the states of the North and the South, and other transnational forums. And membership in the hegemonic bloc also includes the politicians and charismatic figures, along with select organic intellectuals, who provide ideological legitimacy and technical solutions. Below this transnational elite are a small and shrinking layer of middle classes who exercise very little real power but who - pacified with mass consumption - form a fragile buffer between the transnational elite and the world's poor majority. It is in this way that we can speak of a historic bloc in the Gramscian sense as a ruling coalition and a social base in which one group exercises leadership (the TCC) and imposes its project through the consent of those drawn into the bloc. Those from this poor majority who are not drawn into the hegemonic project either through material mechanisms or ideologically are contained or repressed.
The globalist bloc is loosely constituted and the TCC has had difficulty securing its leadership and reproducing hegemony. A necessary condition for the attainment of hegemony by a class or class fraction is the supersession of narrow economic interests by a more universal social vision or ideology, and the concrete coordination of the interests of other groups with those of the leading class or fraction in the process of securing their participation in this social vision. Here, the narrow interests of transnational finance capital (currency speculators, bankers, portfolio investors, etc.) seems to hold out the prospects of frustrating a hegemonic project. As well, a unified social vision has been difficult to secure because distinct sectors of the TCC have often sought different and even conflicting solutions to the problems of global capitalism based in the historic experiences of their regional systems. In this section we shift the narrative from conceptual and theoretical issues to political and conjunctural analysis of the TCC, including strategic debate and tactical differences within its ranks, and in particular, rising splits and factional disputes.
The globalists consolidated ideologically in the early 1980s under the program of the "Washington Consensus" (Williamson, 1993), or global neo-liberalism, first launched by the Reagan and Thatcher regimes. Neo-liberalism as a model for economic restructuring seeks to achieve the conditions in each country and region of the world for the mobility and free operation of capital. The program seeks to harmonize a wide range of fiscal, monetary, industrial, and commercial policies among multiple nations, as a requirement for fully mobile transnational capital to function simultaneously, and often instantaneously, among numerous national borders. In addition to fiscal, monetary, exchange and related measures intended to achieve macroeconomic stability, restructuring includes: liberalization of trade and finances, which opens the economy to the world market; deregulation, which removes the state from economic decision making (but not from activities that service capital); and privatization of formerly public spheres that could hamper capital accumulation if criteria of public interest over private profit is left operative. Neo-liberalism model thus generates the overall conditions for the profitable ("efficient") renewal of capital accumulation through new globalized circuits, and facilitates the subordination and integration of each national economy into the global economy. Neo-liberalism finds its legitimation in neo-classical economics, and in the globalist rhetoric of free trade, growth, efficiency, and prosperity. Global neo-liberalism also entails building a new legal and economic superstructure for the global economy. This process parallels the nation building stage of early capitalism that constructed an integrated national market with common laws, taxes, currency, and political consolidation around a common state. Globalization is repeating this process, but on a world scale.
By the earlier 1990s, the globalists had achieved what appeared as a veritable Gramscian consensus around the neo-liberal project. It was indeed a consensus in that: it represented a congruence of interests among the dominant groups in the global system; these interests were being advanced through institutions that command power (the world's states and the TNS apparatus); and this consensus had achieved ideological hegemony by setting the parameters for, and the limits to, debate among subordinate groups around the world on options and alternative projects. In this sense, the "Washington consensus" reflected the emergence of a new global capitalist hegemonic bloc under the leadership of the TCC. However, cracks in the consensus had become apparent by the close of the decade.
Splits in the Globalist Bloc
The world recession of the 1990s and the sequence of crises, from Mexico in 1995, to Asia in 1997, followed by Russia and Brazil in 1998, exposed the fragility of the world monetary system and caused rising alarm and exposed important contradictions and growing splits in the globalist bloc. The more deeply rooted and complex global capitalism becomes the more each shock to the system generates tensions within the ranks of the TCC. The TCC has become increasingly fragmented in its globalist discourse, in its political vision, and in its ideological coherence. The globalist ruling bloc has three main groups or factions: the free-market conservatives, the neo-liberal structuralists, and the neo-liberal regulationists. The debates that dominate the summits of power in global society do not correspond to the familiar political categories of the pre-globalization era. The distinct position of these factions have less to do with narrow economic-corporate interests than with strategic political issues of class rule. Foremost is the question of how best to structure the new global economy, achieve world order, and assure the long-term stability and reproduction of the system.
All three factions are "globalists" in that their projects are to construct global capitalism and they all speak for the TCC rather than for national capitals. Moreover, all three are neo-liberal in that none question the essential premises of world market liberalization and the freedom of transnational capital. In a nutshell, the free-market conservatives call for a complete global laissez-faire based on an undiluted version of the Washington consensus. The neo-liberal structuralists want a global superstructure that could provide a modicum of stability to the volatile world financial system, adjusting the Washington consensus without interfering with the global economy. And the neo-liberal regulationists call for a broader global regulatory apparatus that could stabilize the financial system as well as attenuate some of the sharpest social contradictions of global capitalism in the interests of securing the political stability of the system. They envision creating a post-Washington globalist consensus. However, even the regulationists do not propose any sort of a global Keynesianism that might involve redistribution or state controls on the prerogatives of transnational capital.
The leading globalist faction are the structuralists, which includes figures such as President Bill Clinton, George Bush (Junior and Senior), Newt Gingrich, World Bank President James Wolfensohn, IMF Managing Director Michel Camdessus, currency speculator George Soros, many Trilateralists and executives of TNCs and major financial institutions. They have had important success in rapidly developing an incipient infrastructure for the global economy, such as the NAFTA and the GATT, establishing the WTO, and expanding the power of the IMF and World Bank. What distinguishes this faction is its adherence to neo-liberal political and economic policies, their concern to build a stable and regulated environment for global accumulation, and their effort to protect world financial institutions from ruin and failure. Of the $1.3 trillion invested daily in currency markets, some two-thirds are held for seven days or less. Only one percent of all speculative transactions stay put for a year or longer. Huge profits are made possible because this instability and quick movement of money results in rapid fluctuations of currency values. It is the prospects of extreme market instability generated by this frenzied global financial activity that the structuralists find so unsettling. "Markets can move like a wrecking ball, knocking over one economy after another," George Soros has warned. "The swings cannot be avoided altogether, but they need to be brought under control" (as cited in Harris, 1999:4).
This fear was brought home by the Asian crash. Propelled by the overnight devaluation of Asian currency and the tidal wave of bankruptcies, the IMF stepped in to expand control over international monetary policies with a $120 billion bailout of Asia (followed by another $42 billion to Brazil). This bailout sparked a cascading debate among the globalists. Conservatives opposed such structural interference in the free market and regulationists raised the tone of their concern over neo-liberal social policies. Much of the discussion focused on stricter regulations of financial institutions, better market supervision of risk management practices, and how to respond to the social fallout resulting from IMF policies. The debate also revealed growing differences between the World Bank and IMF. In fact, the IMF has increasingly been at the center of the debate in the globalist camp. The Fund used the Asian crisis to place greater leverage on Third World countries to further open up to global corporations. In opposition to the IMF's apparent structuralist approach, the World Bank has advanced regulationist arguments. Its 1997 report, The State in a Changing World, questioned the promotion of the "minimalist state" and argued for a larger governmental role in protecting and correcting markets. The report sought to move "attention from the sterile debate of state and market to the more fundamental crisis of state effectiveness" (25). While the report stressed that free market policies should be maintained and in fact deepened, it emphasized that "liberalization is not the same as deregulation" and argued that the state's purpose is in "safeguarding the health of the financial system" (65). In a second report in November 1998 the Bank focused its criticism on particular features of IMF policies. Targeted were the IMF's rapid push for total financial liberalization, the need to control short-term investments, and greater aid for the poor.
The differences here are more of tactics than strategy. The debate is not over free trade, open markets, or long-term foreign investments. Rather it centers on how best to protect the global financial system. Camdessus believes that the current world crisis can be tamed by moderate policy adjustments regarding international regulation and oversight but that IMF policies are basically correct and already showing signs of success in Asian. This is the same approach taken by President Clinton's former Secretary of Treasury Robert Rubin, his replacement, Lawrence Summers, and Britain's Prime Minister Tony Blair. For structuralists grouped around the IMF the global crisis calls for greater centralization. Italian Treasury Minister Carlo Azeglio Ciampi called for the IMF's Interm Committee to become the "embryo" of an economic government for the world. The Interm Committee, which Ciampi chairs, seats finance ministers from 24 core countries. Ciampi argues that the Committee should "become the main channel of communication between the international financial community and national decision-makers" because the crisis makes it "necessary to reinforce the instruments for intervention by international financial institutions." (AFP, 1998). The IMF, in his view, should become this instrument, circumventing any national control over economic policy.
The conservatives are the most ideologically driven sector within the globalists. Representing this trend are former Secretary of State George Schultz, former Citibank CEO and speculator Walter Wriston, former Treasury Secretary and international speculator William Simon, Reagan era economists Lawrence Kudlow and Martin Feldstein, President of the Heritage Foundation Edwin Feulner, and Ian Vasquez of the Cato Institute. Deeply influenced by Milton Freedman, this sector sees any bureaucratic central planning as interference in the pure functioning of the market. As Kudlow has stated: "IMF statism is no better than Soviet statism" (Lerner News Hours). Conservatives argue that the market needs to carry its own risks, and firms must be allowed to fail without being saved by international agencies. It is within this process that a Schumpeterian "creative destruction" occurs. Money is freed from bad management and goes to those who know best how to invest. Bankruptcy, or the destructive side of capitalism, is necessary to free capital to be used to create new wealth. "Capitalism without bankruptcy is like Heaven without Hell," according to Kudlow (ibid). Schultz, Simon and others have actually called for the abolition of the IMF. As argued by Wriston, the power to change government policies is best left to international financiers, not bureaucratic agencies: "Money is asserting its control over government, disciplining irresponsible policies, and taking away free lunches everywhere. If your economic policies are lousy, the market will punish you instantly. I'm in favor of this kind of economic democracy" (1998:202-203).
A Post-Washington Consensus?
While the factional disputes between the structuralists and conservatives grows, since the Asian crash and Russian debacle the regulationists have been growing in importance. Regulationists support free markets, privatization, and the structures of global capitalism. But with expanding poverty they have come to question the complete deregulation of labor markets, cuts in social services, and government's abdication of a modicum of regulation. They want to use global political and regulatory structures to tame the most destructive features of the free market. They recognize the vast inequalities created by unregulated capitalism, and fear the political upheavals that may result.
As the crisis in Asia spread to Russia and Brazil some structuralists like Kissinger and Wolfensohn, along with Harvard economist and WEF administrator Jeffrey Sachs, began to share some of the concerns of the regulationists and debated how best to address the political and social fallout of the crisis. Wolfensohn, perhaps pushed by liberals such as Joseph Stiglitz inside the World Bank, has expressed concern for those thrown into poverty by IMF policies. Following the resignation of Indonesian President Suharto, Henry Kissinger joined the debate, expressing fear that "the indiscriminate globalism of the 1990s may generate a worldwide assault on the very concept of free financial markets" in the same manner that early capitalism "spawned Marxism" (1998). Upset over the political explosions then sweeping Indonesia, Kissinger complained that the "IMF has utterly failed to grasp the political impact of its actions" because of its "excessive emphasis on economics" (Ibid). Supporting Wolfenshohn's position, he argued that states should provide a "social safety net and curb market excesses by regulation" (Ibid).
Some regulationists have actually questioned important aspects of the Washington Consensus as the best way forward for constructing the global economy. This wing of globalists in the United States includes a significant faction of the Democratic Party with such spokespersons as Congressmen Dick Gephart and Dave Bonior, former Secretary of Labor Robert Reich, plus a growing number of influential economists and business figures. In Europe, Asia, and the Third World, it is represented by major labor and social democratic parties, such as Blair's "new" Labor, the social democrats in Germany and France, the ruling coalition in Brazil, and Japan's Vice finance minister Elsuhe "Mr. Yen" Sakakibara. Despite their nationalist and protectionist rhetoric (which is often their legitimizing discourse) these groups do not represent national fractions of capital but are committed to global capitalism. However, they have called for stronger labor standards and environmental protection in the growing number of international agreements, and some argue for a slowdown in capital mobility using different regulatory devices.
For his part, although he is a currency speculator, George Soros has stated that his fellow speculators threaten to destroy the very system that has created their wealth. In The Alchemy of Finance he claims: "Instability is cumulative, so that the eventual breakdown of freely floating exchange is ensured" (1994). As a result he argues the private sector is "ill-suited to allocate international credit" because its goals are to maximize profits and not maintain macro-economic stability. His solution is to create a new International Credit Insurance Corporation that would guarantee loans by setting a ceiling on the amounts insured. Speculative investments beyond insured amounts would be lost through failures, rather than save by IMF bail-outs. Soros understands that further regulation will "outrage the financial community," but in his view: "The main enemy of the open ["democratic"] society is no longer the communist but the capitalist threat" (as cited in Harris, 1999:4).
What these varied pronouncements point to is growing cracks in the Washington consensus, as perhaps best expressed by Joseph Stiglitz, Senior Vice President and chief economist of the World Bank, former Chair of the U.S. Council of Economic Advisors, and a key voice in the regulationist wing. In an April, 1998 speech delivered in Helsinki, Stiglitz launched a major criticism of the Washington Consensus, calling it "incomplete and misleading." Stiglitz, an important organic intellectual of the TCC, argued that "government has an important role in responding to market failures" and "in appropriate regulation, industrial policy, social protection and welfare." Stiglitz called for a post-Washington consensus that would expand the role of government to provide universal education, transfer technology to the public sphere, and enable increases in living standards, improved health, and a healthy environment.
Towards a New Political Configuration?
The "Third Way" and the Politics of Exclusion
Will a new political configuration emerge out of these splits and tendencies within the TCC? What would the politics of such a configuration look like? The rise of the regulationists and the increasing marginalization of the free market conservatives suggest that the first phase in the project of the globalist bloc may be coming to an end. The rise of a new order always involves a "revolutionary" phase that brings down the old one it is replacing, following by a more "moderating" phase in which the new order is stabilized and institutionalized. The revolutionary phase in the rise to hegemony of transnational capital and the TCC was launched by the Reagan and Thatcher regimes (Indeed, the Reagan administration was dominated by free market conservatives). The globalist project appeared in the 1980s in its more dogmatic and ideological form. The institutional structures of the old system were assaulted and brought down with their militancy and extreme form of neo-liberalism; the old system in the period preceding globalization were diverse Keynesian welfare and developmentalist regimes around the world. But by the late 1990s it appeared that the globalist project was moving into a moderating phase in which structuralists and regulationists were beginning to coalesce around a new political configuration.
This configuration is the so-called "Third Way," once again first promulgated in the United States and Great Britain, in the form of the Clinton and Blair regimes, as institutional stabilizers of the new order. By the late 1990s, with the rise of Chancellor Gerhard Schroder in Germany, the Third Way (also called the "New Middle") began to crystalize around this triad as an emergent political project of global capitalism, and to acquire adherents in numerous countries around the world, from Brazil and New Zealand to South Africa, from Spain and Taiwan to Argentina and Japan. Murphy (1999) reviews competing strategic approaches to world order among the global elite. He identifies five political positions: "neo-liberalism"; "Third Way liberalism"; a "softer Third Way liberalism"; a "global social democratic view"; and an "accountable humanitarian" view. He predicts the coming triumph of "Third Way liberalism" (or "soft neo-liberals"), which seems to be a hybrid of what we refer to here as neo-liberal structuralists and regulationists. A Third Way ideology, in his analysis, is likely to become hegemonic in the face of the intractable problems and the legitimacy crisis of neo-liberalism. The program, however, would not question the premises of an ever more open and integrated global economy.
If the globalist project finds its intellectual legitimation in neo-classical economics, the Third Way draws as well on the "new institutional economics" without actually questioning free market principles or challenging the prerogative of capital (it is no wonder that Joseph Stiglitz of the World Bank is also a leading economists from the new institutionalist school). The new institutional, or "post-Keynesian" economics, emphasizes the problems of economic coordination in the free market and their resolution through the management activities of "experts" in the state. Theoretically, this approach argues that the state, which has the authority to create money, influence interest rates, encourage technical development and research through educational and regional policy, and so on, can influence economic activity without interfering directly in the market by creating a more predictable economic environment (see, inter-alia, Cole, forthcoming). In the Third Way discourse, this is "an enabling rather than a bureaucratic government" (Democratic Leadership Council, 1999). Here we may note that the rise of an economic doctrine that emphasizes the coordination of individual producers and the provision of an optimal institutional and infrastructural environment for capital, without challenging the prerogatives of capital, closely mirrors the rise of post-Keynesian/Fordist "flexible" models of accumulation, or the so-called "New Economy." The doctrine emphasizes complex coordination among decentralized and vertically disintegrated production processes, as well as a new and more sophisticated infrastructural environment, such as communication grids and information highways - "goods" which the more "pure" neo-liberal laissez-faire state is ill-equipped to provide.
Third Way politicians have placed unemployment, poverty, and inequality, back on the economic policy agenda, although these are no longer to be tackled through state interventionist mechanisms. The program reaffirms the set of macroeconomic fiscal and monetary policies associated with neo-liberalism, the withdrawal of the state from "economic issues" (state regulation of capital) and the continued rollback of the welfare state. But these aspects are combined with a new emphasis on "social issues" and a quite liberal stance on these matters, emphasizing, in the best bourgeois tradition, equality of opportunity, a new political culture of "market individualism," and local political decentralization. Social programs such as education and health care that generate the "human capital" which high-tech information capitalism requires are given high profile, as is the creation of a "flexible labor market." If, in Frederick Jameson's (1984) famous assessment, post-modernism is the "cultural logic" of late capitalism, the Third Way may turn out to be the emerging "political logic" of global capitalism, with its attendant forms of flexible accumulation.
But can a "Third Way" political configuration stabilize the rule of the TCC? No emergent ruling class can stabilize a new order without developing diverse mechanisms of legitimation and securing a social base - the construction of what Antonio Gramsci called an historic bloc. Such a bloc involves a combination of the consensual integration through material reward for some, and the coercive exclusion of others that the system is unwilling or unable to coopt.
Global society is increasing characterized by a three-tiered social structure. The first tier is made up of some 30-40 percent of the population in core countries and less in peripheral countries, those who hold "tenured" employment in the global economy and are able to maintain, and even expand, their consumption. The second tier, some 30 percent in the core and 20-30 percent in the periphery, form a growing army of "casualized" workers who face chronic insecurity in the conditions of their employment and the absence of any collective insurance against risk previously secured by the welfare state. The third tier, some 30 percent of the population in the core capitalist countries, and some 50 percent or more in peripheral countries, represents those structurally excluded from productive activity and completely unprotected with the dismantling of welfare and developmentalist states, the "superfluous" population of global capitalism (see, inter-alia, Hutton, 1995; Hoogvelt, 1997).
Within this polarized social structure, the Third Way is seeking to secure a firm social base in the first tier, to draw in the second tier, and to contain the third tier. In this "politics of exclusion" the problem of social control becomes paramount. There is a shift from the social welfare state to the social control (police) state, replete with the dramatic expansion of public and private security forces, the mass incarceration of the excluded population (disproportionately minorities), new forms of social apartheid maintained through complex social control technologies, repressive anti-immigration legislation, and so on. It has also entailed, under the Third Way's deceptive discourse of "local politics" and "community empowerment," a shift in the responsibility for social reproduction from the state and society as a whole to the most marginalized communities themselves. This is, as Hoogvelt notes, an attempt to "contain territorially and ideologically" excluded groups, to organize "the poor and the marginalized to care for and contain and control themselves" (1997:149).
In sum, it is not clear that the globalist bloc will consolidate its economic and political hegemony. The fragility of the world monetary system will be a source of growing tensions within the inner circles of the TCC as it searches for a formula that could achieve some regulatory order to the system. However, the principal source of tension will be over how to avert the threat from below. It is not clear in the new epoch how the contradictions of global capitalism will be played out, in particular, those of overaccumulation and worldwide social polarization. But these contradictions and the tensions they generate within the globalist bloc certainly open up new opportunities for emancipatory projects from global labor. An expanding transnational proletariate is the alter ego of the TCC. Struggle between the two will shape the further class development of the new global ruling class and the dynamics of emerging global society.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS: We would like to thank Gioconda Robinson and two anonymous reviewers for their comments on earlier drafts of this essay.
William I. Robinson
Department of Sociology and Anthropology
New Mexico State University
PO Box 30001, MSC 3BV
Las Cruces, NM 88003-8001
wirobins@nmsu.edu
Jerry Harris
DeVry Institute of Technology
3300 North Campbell Avenue
Chicago, IL 60618-5994
jerryharris@igc.org
REFERENCES
Agence France Press. "IMF Must Become 'Embryo' of World Government: Italy." Dispatch dated 12-17-98, datelined Rome.
Amin, Ash (ed). 1994. Post Fordism: A Reader. Oxford: Blackwell.
Arrighi, Giovanni. 1994. The Long Twentieth Century. London: Verso.
Barnet, Richard and Mueller, Ronald. 1974. Global Reach: The Power of the Multinational Corporation. New York: Simon and Schuster.
Bass, Thomas. 1996 "Want to Know About the Future of Money? Talk to Walter Wriston." Wired. Oct, 202-203.
Becker, David, G., Jeff Frieden, Sayre P. Schartz, and Richard L. Sklar. 1987. Postimperialism: International Capitalism and Development in the Late Twentieth Century. Boulder: Lynne Rienner.
Business Week. 1998a. "Psst! Want a Nice Piece of Chaebol?". May 18, 50-51.
-- 1998b. "The Year of the Deal". July 13, 52-53.
Bello, Walden. 1998/99. "The Asian Economic Implosion: Causes, Dynamics, and Prospects," Race and Class, Vol 40, No. 2/3:133-143.
Cole, Ken. Forthcoming. Economy, Environment, Development, Knowledge. London: Routledge.
Cox, Robert, W. 1987. Production, Power, and World Order. New York: Columbia University Press.
-- 1979. "Ideologies and the New International Economic Order: Reflections on Some Recent Literature," International Organization, 33:2, 267-302.
Democratic Leadership Council, Progressive Policy Institute. 1999. "The Third Way," and "The Third Way Goes Global." Documents retrieved on August 26, 1999 from the following web site: http://www.dlcppi.org/ppi/3way/3way.html.
Dicken, Peter. 1998. Global Shift: The Internationalization of Economic Activity, 3rd Edition. New York: Guilford Press.
Domhoff, G., William. 1967. Who Rules America?. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall.
-- 1970. The Higher Circles. New York: Random House.
-- 1978. The Powers that Be. New York: Random House.
Dye, Thomas, T. 1986. Who's Running America. 4th Edition. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice Hall.
Feldstein, Martin. 1998. "Refocusing the IMF". Journal of Foreign Affairs, 77:2 (March/April), 20.
Fennema, Meindert. 1982. International Networks of Banks and Industries. The Hague: Nijhoff.
Gill, Stephen. 1990. American Hegemony and the Trilateral Commission. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Glyn, A. and Sutcliff, B. 1992. "Global But Leaderless? The New Capitalist Order," in Ralph Miliband and Leo Panitch (eds.), New World Order: The Socialist Register. London: Merlin Press.
Goldfrank, Walter. 1977. "Who Rules the World? Class Formation at the International Level." Quarterly Journal of Ideology, 1:2, 32-37.
Gordon, David, M. 1988. "The Global Economy: New Edifice or Crumbling Foundations?" New Left Review. 168, 24-64.
Harris, Jerry. 1998/1999. "Globalisation and the technological transformation of capitalism." Race and Class. 40:2/3, 21-36.
-- 1999. "The Politics of Globalization: Regroupments in the Ruling Class," cy.Rev. 6, 3-10.
Harvey, David. 1990. The Condition of Postmodernity. Oxford: Blackwell.
Hindess, Barry. 1987. Politics and Class Analysis. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Hirst, Paul, and Grahame Thompson. 1996. Globalization in Question. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Hoogvelt, Ankie. 1997. Globalization and the Postcolonial World: The New Political Economy of Development. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Howells, Jeremy, and Michelle Wood. 1992. The Globalisation of Production and Technology. London and New York: Belhaven Press.
Hutton, Will. 1995. The State We're In. London: Jonathan Cape.
Hymer, Stephen. 1979. The Multinational Corporation: A Radical Approach. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Jameson, Frederick. 1984. "Post-Modernism or the Cultural Logic of Late Capitalism." New Left Review. 146, 53-92.
Kissinger, Henry. Oct. 6, 1998. "IMF: Throwing More Fuel on the World Economy." New York Post, 29.
Lerner News Hour. January 18, 1998. Transcript posted at website: Secretariat:Kmp@info.comp.ph.
Marx, Karl, and Frederick Engels. 1970 [1846]. The German Ideology. New York: International Publishers.
Mills, C. Wright. 1959. The Power Elite. New York: Oxford University Press.
Murphy, Craig N. 1999. "Inequality, Turmoil, and Democracy: Global Political-Economic Visions at the End of the Century," New Political Economy. 4:2:289-304.
Patnaik, Prabhat. 1999. "Capitalism in Asia at the End of the Millennium." Monthly Review. 51:3, 1999 (July-August), 53-70.
Robinson, William, I. 1996a. Promoting Polyarchy: Globalization, U.S. Intervention, and Hegemony. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
--- 1996b. "Globalisation: nine These of Our Epoch." Race and Class, 38:2, 13-31.
--- 1997. "A Case Study of Globalisation Processes in the Third World: A Transnational Agenda in Nicaragua." Global Society. 11:1, 61-92.
--- 1998. "Beyond Nation-State Paradigms: Globalization, Sociology, and the Challenge of Transnational Studies." Sociological Forum, 13:4, 561-594.
--- 1998/99. "Latin America and Global Capitalism." Race and Class. 40:2/3, 111-132.
--- 1999. "Capitalist Globalization and the Transnationalization of the State." Paper presented at the "Transatlantic Conference on Historical Materialism and Globalization," University of Warwick, April 15-17, to be published in Mark Rupert and Hazel Smith, The Point is to Change the World: Socialism Through Globalization?. London: Routledge (forthcoming).
Rothkopf, David. 1997. "In Praise of Cultural Imperialism." Foreign Policy, 107:Summer, 38-53.
Sklair, Leslie. 1995. Sociology of the Global System. Second revised edition. Baltimore, Maryland: Johns Hopkins University Press.
--- 1998. "The Transnational Capitalist Class and Global Capitalism: The Case of the Tobacco Industry." Political Power and Social Theory 12:3-43.
Soros, George, [Geoff Shandler (ed.)]. 1998. The Crisis of Global Capitalism: (Open Society Endangered).
-- 1994. The Alchemy of Finance: Reading the Mind of the Market. New York: John Wiley and Sons.
United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD). Various Years. World Investment Report. New York: United Nations/UNCTAD.
Useem, Michael. 1984. The Inner Circle: Large Corporations and the Rise of Business Political Activity in the U.S. and U.K.. New York: Oxford University Press.
Van der Pijl, Kees. 1984. The Making of an Atlantic Ruling Class. London: Verso.
--- 1989. "The International Level," in Tom Bottomore and Robert J. Brym (eds.). The Capitalist Class: An International Study. New York: New York University Press.
-- 1998. Transnational Classes and International Relations. London: Routledge.
Volcker, Paul, with Toyoo Gyohtens. 1992. The World's Money and the Threat to American Leadership. New York: Times Books.
Weiss, Linda. 1998. The Myth of the Powerless State. Ithica, NY: Cornell University Press.
White, Joseph, B. 1998. "Global Mall: 'There are No German or U.S. Companies, Only Successful ONes' - Business Forcers Open Borders as Nationalism Yields to Shared Ambitions -- Big Egos Remain a Big Issue." Wall Street Journal. 1998. May 7, A1
Williamson, John. 1993. "Democracy and the 'Washington Consensus'," World Development 21(8):1329-1336.
Wood, Ellen Meiksins. 1999. "Unhappy Families: Global Capitalism in a World of Nation-States." Monthly Review, 51:3, 1-12.
World Bank. 1992. Global Economic Prospects and Developing Countries. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
-- 1997. The State in a Changing World. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
Wriston, Walter. 1992. Twilight of Sovereignty: how the information revolution is transforming the world. New York: Scribner's.