|
|
|
This paper is one in a series of Occasional Papers in the Center for International Development and Conflict Management’s (CIDCM) Monograph Series. It stems from the Partners in Conflict: Building Bridges to Peace in the Transcaucasus Project. The Center is an interdisciplinary research and training center dedicated to supporting civil society built on a foundation of sustainable peace and development throughout the world. |
|
INTRODUCTIONOil has brought our world to the highest level of industrial and technological competence in a few centuries. It also had a destructive impact on many people’s quality of life. Each time a country finds a new, rich oil reserve; it amasses technological and financial powers and proclaims all the benefits of black gold. However, oil discovery is a two-edged sword. Its revenues can bring prosperity or feed corruption. In this ancient Transcaucasus region on the Caspian Sea, the newly independent states (NIS) which resulted from the breakup of the Soviet Union will find it difficult to create national wealth. Instead, the private wealth of a few may be enhanced because corruption outweighs an interest in social profit sharing.In the twentieth century there are numerous examples of natural resources that have been squandered in the interest of creating private wealth. In the twenty-first century a well planned, coordinated global strategy is needed to avoid repetition of these misfortunes. Clear, comprehensible efforts that include all segments of the population will result in a positive profit allocation. Oil is not just a local currency, but is a powerful foreign exchange. It is our hope that the newly independent states of the Caspian Sea region will not repeat the national crises that led to Indonesian degradation, genocide of the Ogoni in Nigeria, or infrastructure disintegration in Libya. Although prominent in today’s international news, a year ago the Caspian Sea region was considered one of the most remote areas of the world. Now it is viewed next to Kuwait as a potential source of oil and natural gas, with an estimated reserve of 200 billion barrels of oil and 7.89 trillion cubic meters of natural gas. This is equal to all the oil reserves in Iraq, and the combined natural gas reserves of the United States and Mexico, with an estimated value of 4 trillion dollars. While great riches are possible, they come at a price. Resource-rich Azerbaijan must rely on its neighbors for export. Such wealth can create high cash flow and handsome rewards for investors. Short term experiences with a market economy often reveal greed and corruption, leading to the enrichment of a few. Ensuring the equal distribution of wealth and greater freedom of choice requires an active civil society in a stable democracy. Can the newly independent states, whose twentieth century experience has been non democratic create this type of environment ? Furthermore, this region’s energy resources are closely affected by a number of outside influences. Russia’s relation to former Soviet Republics, Iran’s relations with the west (especially the U.S.), international politics, the economy in Turkey, and China’s needs and resources are a few examples of third party interests in Caspian oil and gas reserves development. For inexperienced new states, these considerations provide a set of complex challenges. Controversy over Caspian oil is not new. In the latter nineteenth
and early parts of the twentieth century, oil barons like the Nobel brothers
and companies such as the Royal Dutch Shell shipped Caspian oil. The oil
was transported in the world’s first operational oil tankers, developed
by the Nobel brothers. During both world wars, Germany’s inability
to fuel its war efforts with Caucasian oil played a significant role in
her defeat. And the period following the wars was marked by fierce
competition between oil companies, ethnic conflict, and corruption-conditions
not unlike those found today.
EXPECTATIONSMost observers of the Transcaucaus are convinced that Caspian oil will be a positive influence in the development of the region’s economics. It is assumed that enormous cash investments will result in revenues which will revive expanding economies, bring prosperity, and stimulate regional cooperation. This has not happened historically; however nor is such an environment found in most oil-rich regions. Some people are looking for solutions to the current ethnopolitical conflicts, as well as assurance of no future recurrences. Most of these protracted conflicts were merely submerged during the 70+ years of Soviet rule and resurfaced violently during the Soviet Union dissolution. If they are once again held in abeyance, this time to placate investors, they will surely reappear and could wreak havoc on constructed pipelines.DECISIONS ABOUT PIPELINESOil must reach world markets from the region. What routes will carry this oil from its sea bed to the world’s refineries and on to markets ? Each Caucasian (and Central Asian) locale has its preference. External players are trying to exert influence to ensure that selected paths best meet their needs. A brief look at some of these factors reveal that: Russia prefers routes designed to pipe the oil through the north and is even willing to build a by-pass around troublesome Chechnya. The U.S. and her western allies as well as Georgia, Azerbaijan, and Turkey, prefer the western route which requires upgrading the pipeline through Georgia (this may be the cheapest option). Routes to the south are favored by the nations around the Gulf; pipelines already exist in Iran. Therefore, it is economically feasible, and Asian markets would be served by this latter plan.In establishing routes, an analysis of cost is necessary and costs vary. A route from Azerbaijan to Turkey might run around $3 billion; a pipeline from Azerbaijan to the Gulf would cost about the same. A northern route from Azerbaijan to Russia by way of the Black Sea could cost about $1 billion. The most costly route would go through Kazakstan to China, at a projected total cost of $6 billion. For China, this might not be economically rewarding, but would be strategically important. Amounts like these cannot come from within an impoverished, rebuilding region; they must be invested by oil companies and international investors. Therefore, decisions will likely be strongly influenced by oil consortia. This will happen within the sphere of political realities. REGIONAL ECONOMIC PICTUREThe positive impacts of oil sales include cheap energy, greater independence, hard-currency influx, internal infrastructure improvements, and improved balance of payments. Responsible governments may use the opportunities to sell oil and gas to revive failing economies and provide a needed social safety net. This money would be a real blessing to impoverished Caspian states during their painful reform period.Unfortunately, a look at economic and regional histories show that petrodollars have not always been used constructively. The international history of petroleum development demonstrates that the effects of oil exports can be unexpectedly negative for the economy and society of oil producing countries. Indeed, according to Noreng (1981): ...the development of a domestic petroleum industry appears to create serious structural problems in the economy. The main characteristic is a general loss of industrial competitiveness, with a potential for a gradual de-industrialization of the countries concerned. The process is essentially due to two sets of factors: a general cost pressure in the economy caused by the domestic use of oil revenues; and a rising exchange rate, due to financial surpluses (i.e., revenues that are not use domestically) as well as due to deliberate policy. Thus, whether oil revenues are used in the domestic economy or are exported, they represent a problem for traditional industry when they reach a certain magnitude.(page 32) Currently, a term little known in the region, "Dutch disease," may soon become well know throughout the Caspian region. Indeed, the effect of natural gas exports on the Dutch economy is a classic example of the negative overall effect of energy exports on a national economy. In the first effect of cash flows associated with oil development, national currencies become very strong in relation to the U.S. dollar. Imports then become cheaper while local products become more expensive because they cannot compete with imported goods. In addition, non-oil exports become expensive and non competitive in international markets. The result is that most branches of the national economy outside of oil exploration and its transportation quickly deteriorate--hence the "Dutch disease." Interestingly, during the oil embargo imposed on Iran after the nationalization of Anglo-Iranian Oil Company (AIOC) in 1951, the Iranian economy did not perform too badly due to rising non-oil exports. This period was even called "the period of industrial recovery". (Elm,1992, p.272) While for the well-developed economy of the Netherlands, the effect was not fatal, Caspian countries may be in serious jeopardy. Currently, most of region’s industries are at a standstill, working equipment is outdated, and products are not competitive on the world market. "Dutch disease" may further aggravate this situation, since modernization of industries outside the oil sector could be considered an unattractive enterprise because most required goods can more easily be purchased abroad. A strong government commitment is needed to invest petrodollars in industries and such an investment does not always yield a quick return. At the same time, there is increasing social pressure to improve living standards and enable a higher quality of life. This process may cause an economy to become closely tied to the
cyclical oil sector and thus highly susceptible to changes in world oil
prices, since the "oil market is a commodity market and, as such, has always
gone through cyclical booms and busts" (Wilson, 1987, p 2). Any significant
drop in oil prices leads to a sharp drop in government revenues and to
foreign borrowing from foreign lenders (often using expensive commercial
credit). In the early 1980s, the Venezuelan government’s policy was
to limit inflation attributable to "Dutch disease." However, this
policy eventually limited economic growth, causing this large oil exporter
to become the world’s largest debtor in per-capita terms (Randall, 1987,
pp. 187, 189). As foreign debt grows, an increasingly larger proportion
of the petrodollars will be spent on repayment.
Importantly, multinationals do not as a rule process oil in the country of exploration because they wish to avoid construction costs and environmental damage claims. Also local economies have very small energy and petroleum markets so the real markets for Caspian oil are far away in the West, or in Southeast Asia. Oil companies are more concerned with how to take the crude oil out to seaports than with the development of oil-processing facilities. While there is hope that oil development projects will create jobs in the oil-processing and petrochemical industry, this hope may be unfounded if governmental requirements are not designed and implemented to ensure local participation. Another source of jobs associated with the oil industry is the services sector, including hotels, communications, and transportation. Still, the numbers employed in these areas will not be large enough, especially in relatively big countries. Oil producing countries with smaller populations (Azerbaijan, Turkmenistan) are in a much better position than bigger nations (Kazakstan, Uzbekistan), which already are experiencing serious unemployment. POLITICAL ASPECTSIt is evident that this combination of economic factors may create an explosive social situation. The collapse of the agricultural sector may cause an out migration from the rural to urban areas and oil-producing enclaves, looking for jobs. Since jobs may not be found in urban areas, a reliable social safety net is essential. Caucasians have suffered ethnopolitical population transfer, too.Another side effect may be the exacerbation of existing social and ethnic
conflicts, due to disparities in standards of living between oil-producing
enclaves and capital cities (financial centers) and other regions. A relative
deprivation phenomenon is a powerful source of group mobilization, especially
when petrodollars distribution is felt to be unfair and the system is perceived
to be engulfed in corruption. Such is the case in the Movement for
Survival of Ogoni in Nigeria (MOSOP).
The lesson of the Iranian revolution was that the Shah
was the principal 'client' of the United States [he was supported, but
when] he was faced with internal, fundamentalist force the United States
was either unwilling or unable to support him and he was brushed aside
with relative ease (p.282).
..the black gold may tempt the elites to buy short-term support through some conspicuous social expenditures and the awarding of congressional seats to opposition parties while avoiding the sacrifices required by genuine reforms. Unless major changes are made in the next few years, the country could exhaust its most accessible reserves without achieving the populist goals of the Mexican Revolution. Moreover, a country, whose leaders occasionally blame their problems on "U.S. imperialism" or the machinations of transnational firms will be denied a convenient scapegoat" (Grayson, 1980, p 234) IMPORTANCE OF REGIONAL COOPERATIONWithout significant regional cooperation, the Caspian governments may use oil proceeds to build their militaries, and make extensive purchases of weapons. Azerbaijan will definitely strengthen its army in the hope of expelling Armenian forces from occupied territories. Facing a threat due to Afghanistan’s instability; the nations of Turkmenistan, Uzbekistan and Kazakstan may also increase their military expenditures.Stronger armies are a burden in peaceful times. Commanders claim that military victory can resolve social conflicts, and encourage governments to seek a military solution or to employ one in the event of conflict. Military expenditures may also lead to a regional arms race that could devastate the regional economy and destabilize the region. The Middle East, a bonanza market for oil sales, is a highly unstable region: arms purchases from developed countries represented 25% of the world arms market in 1985, whereas those from the Middle East amounted to 35%, with 20% of the region’s Gross Domestic Product going to weapons purchases (Mernissi,1996, p 257). Regional cooperation, on the other hand, may increase trust and permit
the development of diplomatic mechanisms for dealing with potential crises,
thereby reducing potential violence. Important, too, is coordination of
the export marketing of petroleum-related products. In Gulf and Middle
East countries with similar petroleum resources, construction of petrochemical
complexes resulted in an oversupply of products on the market, which seriously
hindered prices and profitability. Caspian oil-producing countries should
coordinate their activities in this area for their mutual benefit.
CONCLUSIONMany observers expect the governments of the Caspian region to invest proceeds from the sale of energy projects into the development of non-oil related branches of the national economy; provide citizen participation in the distribution of energy-related income; fund social services; improve infrastructure; and increase standards of living for all. However, most of the export revenues may fall into the hands of a few, leaving the general population with little of the national wealth.As we have seen, countries that encounter oil and turn the accident of location into national wealth have mature democratic governments, strong environmental regulations, and self-contained control of oil extraction and processing. For the Caspian region, these three characteristics are still in the future. Therefore, since current demand for oil is not high, time is on their side. Slower oil development and faster rebuilding of infrastructure could significantly help to make the equation, "petrodollars=prosperity" a reality. Norway’s lessons should be carefully compared to those of Venezuela and Nigeria. The key is patience. So many options are being presented, with large dollar signs attached; evaluating who, when, how much, and, most critically, by which route, will require deep and careful thought. In Iraq Saddam Husssein wasted most of his oil proceeds on armaments and military build-up. By way of contrast; Norway distributed oil proceeds to citizens by paying for medical and educational expenses, keeping unemployment low, and investing heavily in capital programs, infrastructure, and social projects. It is evident that how petrodollars are used in the Caspian will be a crucial test that will determine the regions’s future for years to come, and influence stability. We have seen much evidence of the consequences of instant wealth.
We are acutely aware of the need for greater democratization, and we are
also cognizant of how closely current conditions mirror those of past failures
for the Caspian oil industry. What do we suggest ? The leaders
of the Caucasian and Central Asian new states must break with the past,
demand human and environmental investment before decimating their land
and ignoring people. It can not be business as usual: the oil must
stay in a local workforce and develop infrastructure that supports continued
growth in a sound environment. Western governments can help by supporting
democratization, particularly private land ownership and the right of eminent
domain; the fair market value of land must be guaranteed to each farmer
or fisherman. The opportunity to ensure these exchanges and policies exists.
Plentiful oil ensures that the region has time to move wisely and slowly
and follow the Norwegian model.
|
References:
Barnes.(1995). Indonesia. The Political Economy of Energy, Oxford University Press: Oxford. Brooks, Geraldine.(1994). "Slick Alliance: Shell’s Nigerian Fields Produce
Few Benefits for Region’s Villagers". Wall Street Journal,
May 6, 1994.
Ellman,Michael. (1981). "Natural Gas, Restructuring and Re-industrialization: The Dutch Experience of Industrial Policy". In Oil or Industry: Energy, Industrialization and Economic Policy in Canada, Mexico, the Netherlands, Norway and the United Kingdom. Eds. T. Barker and V. Brailovsky. Academic Press: London. Elm, Moustafa. (1992). Oil, Power and Principle: Iran’s Oil Nationalization and Its Aftermath. Syracuse University Press: Syracuse, NY. Grayson,George. (1989). The Politics of Mexican Oil. University of Pittsburgh Press: Pittsburgh. Mallakh, Ragaei El. (1979). Qatar: Development of an Oil Economy. St. Martin’s Press: NY. Mernissi, Fatema. (1996). "Palace Fundamentalism and Liberal Democracy." Development and Change, 27: 251-256. Noreng, Oystein (1981) "Petroleum Revenues and Industrial Income", In Oil or Industry: Energy, Industrialization, and Economic Policy in Canada, Mexico, and the Netherlands, Norway, and United Kingdom. Eds. T. Barker and V. Brailovsky. Academic Press: London. Ossify, M.G. (1995). "The Impact of Oil Export on the Economy of OPEC Countries: An Empirical Investigation." The Indian Economic Journal: 42, Note 3. Randall, Laura. (1987). The Political Economy of Venezuelan Oil. Praeger: NY. Wilson, Ernest. (1987). "The Petro-Political Cycle." In Energy Resources Development: Politics and Policies. Eds. R. Ender and J. Kim. Quorum Books: NY. Zedillo, Ernesto. (1981) "Optimal Oil Depletion and Foreign Indebtedness:
The Case of Mexico." In Oil or Industry: Energy, Industrialization
and Economic Policy in Canada, Mexico, and the Netherlands, Norway and
the United Kingdom. Eds. T. Barker and V. Brailovsky. Academic
Press: London.
|
|
|