The Social Security conundrum
Curt
Mudgeon March 2005 President
Bush has touched the “third rail” and the Washington political world is in a
tizzy. As customary when dealing with
difficult problems, Capitol Hill denizens, spin-doctors, pundits, and other
propagandists are spewing volumes of thick smog to muddle the
atmosphere. While some advance that
the system is not in crisis and does not need to be fixed, others acknowledge
a crisis but argue that it can be easily repaired. Of course, all this is rubbish. The problem exists, it is serious, and solutions are not
easy. But a search for a solution is
a sensitive matter because it is bound to expose decades of government irresponsibility
and to make the next election cycle perhaps more interesting than usual. Senior congressmen, who have a particular
dislike for “interesting” reelection campaigns, are thus doing all they can
to confuse the electorate. They are
skilled at it, and they might well succeed in blocking any sensible
reconsideration of a flawed program that has outlived its function and should
have been replaced with a true pension plan some twenty years ago. Facts,
however, insist on being facts, political smog notwithstanding. Under current regime, the Social Security
payments start exceeding the receipts in 2018. To meet its obligations, the program then has to dig into its
surplus, which will last about twenty years.
By 2038, the system is broke and begins to run a sharply growing
yearly deficit. This scenario is not
contrived. It is governed by
reliable, highly-predictable demographic data. While 16.5 people were contributing to the program for each
beneficiary in 1950, this ratio has fallen to a current 3.4 and will continue
to fall. It does not take an advanced
degree in demography to understand how the baby-boomers’ retirement, the
lower birth rate of the following generations, the increase in life
expectancy, and the ballooning payments of disability benefits can have
created this situation. So, why
is the Congress so reluctant to consider the president’s invitation to reform
the system, and why is there such a divergence of opinions about what to
do? First, there is no Social
Security surplus to be tapped in 2018.
Although the program has collected more than it has paid since its
inception, the excess, which currently amounts to more than a trillion
dollars, has been loaned to the government---as stipulated by law. Over the decades, it has been freely used
as if it were some congressional slush fund and has become part of the
national debt. For example, it has
helped financing the ubiquitous Robert C. Byrd buildings, the Robert C. Byrd
dam, the many Robert C. Byrd centers, and other Robert C. Byrd edifices that
grace the West Virginia landscape. It
is easy to find many other instances of similar government extravagance, one
being the Boston Big Dig, a boondoggle dear to Senator Edward Kennedy, which
Washington has subsidised to the tune of nine billion dollars. Such egregious uses of federal funds, a
privilege of seniority in both houses of Congress, not only buy votes, but
also discourage possible challengers at reelection time. It is little wonder that “King of Pork”
Robert C. Byrd, first elected to the House in 1946, has been a fixture in the
Senate since 1958. For the many
Congress spendthrifts, the time has come to face the music, and they would
rather hide, or demagog, or, even better, grandstand about baseball and
steroids. In 2018,
the federal government will owe Social Security some three trillion dollars,
and that money will have to be paid back over time to fulfill the program’s
obligations, while the debt will continue to grow. At that time, keeping the program alive will require a choice
among the nonexclusive options of reducing the benefits, increasing the age
of eligibility, raising the tax, diverting funds from nonessential programs,
or increasing the national debt. Many
congressmen show little taste for such options, and some would rather do
nothing now and let the situation deteriorate to the point where they are
“forced” to make bad choices. Others
would favor measures politically unpalatable on a condition of “bipartisan”
responsibility as a protection against an irate electorate pointing
accusatory fingers at one party or the other. Unfortunately for them, the current political mood of
Washington is more one of guerilla warfare than one of cooperative
bipartisanship, as the head of the Democratic National Committee recently
professed to hating Republicans, while prominent congressional Democrats promised
to block any Republican proposals. Regardless
of Congress likes or dislikes, the matter of solvency, which gets worse with
time, suggests that Social Security cannot be kept alive for very long. By 2030, there will be two FICA payers for
each benefit recipient. Raising the
12.4% tax is impractical. The
argument that an employee could sustain a modest increase of that tax because
he pays “only” half of it ignores that the other half paid by his employer
either comes out of this employee’s wages, or from a reduction of the number
of employees, or from a higher price of products and services. In the end, the employee-consumer bears
most of the burden of the tax increase, and may even find it more difficult
to be employed. The “soak the rich”
proposal to remove or raise the cap on wages subject to the Social Security
tax is not any better. The question
is not whether people who make more than $90,000 a year can or cannot afford
to pay for the tax increase. The
reality is that these people are likely investors in productive enterprises
that help grow the economy and create jobs.
Reducing the capacity to invest adversely impacts economic
vitality. Finally, increasing a tax on
income is one of the best ways to decrease the incentive to work hard. In truth, the Social Security conundrum is
twofold. On one side, there is the
pickle in which politicians find themselves.
In the face of a difficult problem to which they have largely
contributed, many worry more about political image, elections, and power than
about solutions. Twenty three years
ago, a bipartisan commission “saved” the system in rather unimaginative ways,
namely, with a tax hike, an increase in the age of eligibility, and the
taxation of the benefits received by people with incomes above a certain
threshold. At that time, anyone with
a brain knew from reliable demographic projections that the system had not
been saved and that it would fail a thirty years later. But, in politics, thirty years is a safe
time stretch. Most voters do not remember
what happen thirty years ago. They cannot hold a grudge that long against
those who fooled them by claiming to have saved a program that should not
have been saved but replaced with an honest retirement system. What was done in 1982, however ill-advised,
is no longer practical, smoke and mirrors notwithstanding. Such is the politicians’ side of the
conundrum. The other side, which so far has not gotten that
much congressional attention, is the plight of the younger generations. Because of the pyramidal nature of the
system, tweaking the tax will not have a significant effect on the life of
the program. At the same time,
actuarial data will require continuous reductions of the benefits and
increases of the age of eligibility.
If no significant reform takes place, younger workers must expect
little return for their contributions---a good case for a tax rebellion. To add insult to injury, they will have to
find employment or stay employed at an age that, right or wrong, employers
too often consider unsuitable. By
allowing a fraction of the Social Security tax to go to a private retirement
account, it is their predicament that President Bush’s proposal
addresses. Predictably, Democrats vehemently oppose the
president’s idea as they oppose any idea that originates in the White
House. In this case, however, their
opposition has deeper motives. They
see private accounts as a threat to their vision of governance, which has
been consistently moving for the past forty years towards a social-democrat
model that disfavours people’s independence from government. They also are more concerned with “saving”
Social Security than with John Doe’s retirement because Social Security has
served as the emblem of their goodness of heart since the 1930s. In that context, the president’s proposal,
which might well be a first step towards the demise of the program, cannot
rally much Democrat support, and neither can the prospect that the funds
diverted to private accounts will escape congressional control. Since such motives cannot be brought
forward in the debate, opponents of change invoke the adverse effect that
reduced contributions will have on program solvency. But this effect can only be transient
since workers who take the private-account option will draw Social Security
benefits adjusted for their lower contributions. The proposal for private accounts seems quite
popular among the young.
Surprisingly, seniors already retired or about to retire do not see it
so favorably, although their benefits would remain untouched. This is partly imputable to an aggressive
AARP propaganda campaign that only reflects the lobby’s leftist
predilections. Perhaps as important
is the sentiment widespread among those born during the Great Depression that
only the government can reliably guarantee a retirement safety net. In a way, this belief is buttressed by the
property unique to the government to get deep in debt with seeming
impunity. In his campaign for reform,
President Bush will need much help, and particularly from those in Congress
who enjoy the seniors’ trust. Now, if you think that the Social Security conundrum
is a hard nut to crack, think of the coming Medicare-Medicaid crunch. |